Posts tonen met het label Hugh Pavletich. Alle posts tonen
Posts tonen met het label Hugh Pavletich. Alle posts tonen

dinsdag 17 april 2012

Take-over

Central government has taken over responsibility for fixing downtown Christchurch. Here's Chris Hutching's take:
No more $500 million light rail schemes or reverting one-way streets to two-way at a cost of $91 million.
Today, Canterbury Earthquake Recovery Minister Gerry Brownlee ditched the Christchurch City Council’s recovery plan.
Mayor Bob Parker put a brave face on things at the media conference today, even claiming the city plan’s “visionary” Volume 1 themes had been enshrined.
The new arrangement would be a “true partnership”, he said.
But the reality is that the actual proposals contained in Volume 2 have been thrown out of the recovery scenario.
They included the mayor’s pet light rail project that would have soaked up $500m of the $2 billion recovery plan.
I'm more than happy to see the back of the woollier Council proposals; I hope Hutching's right that we're binning both the changes in the one-way system and the light rail scheme.

I don't think Hugh Pavletich is far off the mark in pushing for substantial devolution to local boards to help get things done; I'd have leaned that way rather than to a new centralized control body.

But at least the new board's talking some of the right talk for downtown. The new team's emphasis on quickly establishing the sites for major public infrastructure pieces like the convention centre is important - the hotels won't want to move until they know where these kinds of facilities will be placed. And restaurants will want to know where the hotels are going to be.

I really hope that, when they talk about land amalgamation, they give some thought to Tabarrok's dominant assurance contracts rather than compulsory acquisition. Applying Tabarrok's model to land acquisition, Councils effectively buy options to purchase a lot of properties, then exercise those options on the best set of properties for the development.

We invoke eminent domain to avoid hold-out problems where the last owner to sign on for a major development can extract a good part of the project's surplus. Buying options across a lot of potential sites can be more expensive, but eliminates the hold-out problem where different bundles of properties could serve similar purpose. So long as the strike price is a fair one, you've a dominant strategy in selling the option to the government. If the government doesn't exercise the option on your property, you're up by the option payment; if they do, you're no worse off.

See also Bruce Benson's work on solutions to land amalgamation problems that do not do violence to existing ownership rights.

I hope that whatever aesthetic vision the planners might want to impose is done by setting examples in the design of the new public facilities rather than by mandating standards. I'd be really happy to hear an announcement that they're planning structures designed around innovative wooden laminates. U Canterbury is doing some work in the area if they're looking for people with expertise.

A final hope is that the new agency pushes hard to get insurance issues sorted. Does full replacement cover mean coverage to the ex ante or ex post building code? Getting a few declaratory judgements on issues facing a lot of property owners could help get things moving.

Perhaps the best thing about the take-over is that it's now very clear what voters need to do come the next election if Christchurch remains buggered. Parker's already toast, at least according to iPredict. If Christchurch is back on track come the next election, vote National. Otherwise, don't. At least for Canterbury, the next election ought now to wind up being a referendum on how they've handled Christchurch.

NZIER reports on the latest economic indicators for post-quake Christchurch.

Here's the latest on building consents. See also Bill Kaye-Blake.
More building consents than elsewhere in the country, but we're not even meeting the numbers of consents issued through most of the 2000s. National hasn't long to get things moving.

zondag 11 maart 2012

Development constraints

Among Christchurch's larger ongoing post-earthquake problems is a lack of housing. Sections are only slowly coming on-stream and are expensive. Whatever Council or CERA says about how many years' worth of housing stock we're soon to have available, prices seem the better signal of real scarcity, though I'd look to selling prices rather than rental rates as better capturing fundamentals.

And so it was a bit surprising to see that Council's knocked back a developer's plan to build a new subdivision in Papanui. I lived around the corner from the proposed development for a year before we moved to South Brighton. It always seemed odd that somebody reckoned the land's highest value use was in market gardens rather than houses: more than 10 hectares of farmland sitting in the middle of residential sections and well serviced by Cranford Street and Main North Road, with lots of amenities nearby. But it was always an artefact of zoning and planning regs. From today's Press:
Cera chief executive Roger Sutton said the Cranford Basin land was excluded from the October announcement because at that time it was considered it would be faster to develop other areas, given the make-up of the land.
Christchurch City Council strategy and planning group general manager Mike Theelen said he believed the commissioners had identified the Cranford Basin as an area to investigate further, rather than one that should definitely be developed. The basin was a low-lying area and was getting lower, he said.
"There is a variety of constraints in there that suggest it shouldn't be residential, or that it's not suitable for urban development."
The Northern Arterial motorway extension was planned to go through the middle of the basin, he said, but it would not come close to Peebles' land.
The land had been flood-prone for decades and there was no pressing need to start development in areas that were difficult to work, he said.
"The last thing we want to create is something no one wants to live in because it's deemed to be an earthquake-prone suburb."
He believed no council would want to "abandon its principles" because of an earthquake.
The council was trying to ensure enough land was released into the market to meet demand without overextending the council's ability to provide infrastructure, which would raise costs and rates, he said.
"It's about sending signals to the market about where the councils intend to see development heading. A balance between giving a framework and allowing the market to operate within that framework."
The article also noted the land isn't subject to liquefaction.

I'd love The Press's eventual follow-up to let us know a few additional things:

  • Flood risk:
    • Is the developer willing to put in enhanced storm drainage to deal with this? If so, are there capacity constraints on the nearby sewer mains that would prevent privately provided drains from emptying?
    • Can we reconcile claims that the land is immune to liquefaction and Council's view that it would be earthquake prone?
    • If the section is "difficult to work", is there some differential difficulty falling on Council relative to the developer? It could be that it's easy to put houses on the land but that sewerage would require a pumping station, the burden of which would fall on Council. But it's otherwise hard to explain why a developer would want to develop a section that's "difficult to work". 
  • Speed of development:
    • Does anything prevent the developer putting in his own roading and sewerage so as not to burden council, perhaps in exchange for rates concessions for future residents? 
    • If the reason for banning the development is that Council hasn't the capacity to get the roading in in timely fashion, why not facilitate alternative arrangements allowing the developer to do it?
    • If the constraint is capacity in adjoining trunk line water and sewerage, that's more difficult to sort in the short term through developer levies. 
  • Sending signals
    • Council is currently sending a strong signal that it doesn't really want anybody putting in housing for the folks having to leave the Red Zone. That is likely not Council's intent, but successions of stories of people barred from building houses sends the signal regardless of intent.
    • Theelen says the last thing he wants is to set something up and have nobody want to live there. If Council's investing substantial infrastructure resources, then it does have some skin in the game. But surely the developer is reasonably placed to gauge whether there would be demand for the houses he'll build and wouldn't want to develop if nobody would want to live there. What does Theelen know about what consumers want that Peebles, the developer, doesn't? How does he know that he knows more than the developer about likely demand for the developer's sections?
Bottom line is that if development is being held up because of our current way of financing and installing infrastructure like residential roads and sewerage, we probably ought change models. It's completely believable that Council is at its production possibilities frontier on roading and sewerage; half of the east side of town needs new roads and sewers. Why not let developers push that frontier out by flying in more crews and kit to do the work? 

Hugh Pavletich recommends Municipal Utility Districts as a way of financing infrastructure. As brief refresher, MUDs basically let developers take on the up-front costs of infrastructure by issuing bonds backed by future tax streams from the new development. The developer sets up an initial Board, which is replaced in due course by election by those living in the district. The Board sets tax rates to pay off the bonds that financed the infrastructure in the development; presumably, if set up here, the MUD rates would offset some of the normal Council rates as the MUD would be providing services normally otherwise provided by Council. The section selling prices are then lower, partially because there's a future tax stream liability attached to them; if the MUD can finance things more cheaply than homeowner mortgages, it makes sense. Otherwise, you could just bundle everything into a higher selling price for the section and have folks take on higher mortgages in exchange for a lower stream of Council rates going forward.

This all works either if Council wouldn't face borrowing constraints in underwriting development bonds, or if bonds backed by future tax streams from homeowners in the MUD could find buyers at prices that didn't make the whole thing unaffordable, or if homeowners could take on sections with higher up-front costs and slightly lower ongoing rates.

The best academic summary I can find on MUDs, now a bit dated, says they do a lot to increase the supply of land for development by circumventing the Council-capacity bottleneck on infrastructure; they also consequently reduce the selling price of new sections. But they can come at the cost of less regional coordination on main trunk infrastructure - sewer mains and highways. 

If Council capacity in providing infrastructure for the new development is the real constraint in opening up sections like Peebles' proposed development, MUDs expand the production possibilities frontier. The developer could then finance the enhanced storm drains and pumping station that might be necessary for a low-lying area while not drawing away already overextended Council infrastructure resources. That doesn't help if the City's complementary infrastructure like sewerage and water mains in the area aren't up to handling another 169 houses' needs; it's hard to tell from what's been reported where the real constraint is. It would be useful to know just what the bottlenecks are.